Argentina

Страница: 1/6

ARGENTINA Argentina has experienced slow economic growth since the 1940s. By the mid-1970s long-term growth declined noticeably, and in the last half of the 1980s the country suffered its longest period of stagnation in the century.

Savings and investment rates fell precipitously from the mid-1970s until 1989. Argentines, responding to the unstable macroeconomic environment, increasingly saved and invested abroad.

Labor productivity fell ang poverty worsened.

This economic performance was tranceable to chronic public sector deficits and endemic inflation.

Public sector deficits in the late 1970s ranged from 10 to 14 percent of GDP, and in the early 1980s surpassed IS percent of GDP.

After the return to constitutional democracy in 1983, public demands to control inflation were translated into four successive stabilization programs.

All failed to eradicate inflation, and each ended in a more virulent inflation than the one preceding it.

The main reason for these failures was the inability of the stabilization programs to redress rapidly and permanently the public sector structural deficit.

Structural deficits emerged from the post-war organization of the economy.

Economic policy from the 1940s was used to propagate rules and transfers favoring the interests of private groups with access to power.

By the early 1980s public expenditures approached 40 percent of GDP.

Unionized labor benefitted from high wages, guaranteed employment, and rigid rules governing hiring and dismissals.

Industry benefitted from highly protected markets, tax exemptions through special promotion regimes, subsidized credit-or effective grants, as many loans were not collected-subsidized inputs from public enterprises, and high prices on sales to public enterprises. Housing contractors and middleclass home buyers benefitted from enormous public transfers through earmarked taxes and effective grants through the Housing Bank.

Tobacco growers, sugar growers, the merchant marine, and other small interest groups enjoyed special tax breaks.

Consumers enjoyed below-cost tariffs from public enterprise and lax collectioll practices.

Provincial governments could avail themselves of costless credit from the provincial banks, which the central bank reimbursed.

The military enjoyed expanding budgets, especially over 1976-82, as well as management perquisites in state companies they controlled.

By 1989 subsidies through the budget, tax exemptions, agriculcural regulations, public enterprise tariffs, and central bank rediscounts were estimated to amount to roughly 8 percent of GDP--the equivalent of some $8 billion.

The growth of the state and concomitant rents and subsidies, along with the capital flight provoked by an inconsistent exchange rate policy, were financed during the late 1970s largely by external borrowing through the expanding Eurodollar market at low or even negative real international interest rates.

This permitted the government to run large deficits and sustain a revalued exchange rate with relatively low levels of inflation in the second half of the 1970s.

An abrupt end to voluntary foreign commercial credit in the early 1980s and the sudden rise in real international interest rates provoked a financial collapse and placed additional pressure on public finances.

The situation was complicated by the South Atlantic War.

The loss of external finance and lack of adjustment meant the treasury had to resort to increased inflationary finance through monetary creation.

The private sector, in an effort to avoid the resulting inflation tax, gradually withdrew its resources from the financial system and reduced its real holdings of currency ; this, together with the negative effects of inflation on real tax collections, made Argentina's economy progressively more unstable in the 1980s. Even though the deficit fell from near 20 percent of GDP in the early 1980s to an average of about 10 percent over 1987-89, the base for the inflation tax shrank even faster--efforts to reduce the deficit were not fast or permanent enough to convince the private sector that savings in domestic currency would not be eroded by inflation.

Inflation became high and unpredictable, and the main impediment to the recovery of private savings and investment.

The decade ended with two episodes of hyperinflation in 1989. Post-1989 Structural Reforms Tbe present administration took office in July 1989 during a traumatic hyperinflation--July inflation alone was 200 percent. This culminated a decade-long crisis in public finance.

Реферат опубликован: 23/09/2007